November 1998 SCSB# 390
Chapter 9 Measuring the Effectiveness of Nonprice Promotion of U.S. Agricultural Exports Using a Supply-side Approach
GNP Function Approach to Modeling Agricultural TradeIn this section, we lay out essential features of Kohli's GNP function approach to modeling international trade (Kohli 1991). Imports are regarded as a variable input into a production process that results in exports as a variable output distinct from output produced for domestic consumption. Variable inputs and outputs are treated as netputs, so variable inputs can be viewed as negative outputs. Capital and labor are treated as quasifixed inputs and are positively measured. Assuming that individual producers are competitive profit maximizers, and that the aggregate of all agricultural producers behaves as though it were a competitive profit-maximizing firm, profit is given by: where p denotes the vector of variable netput prices, z and w represent quantity and price vectors of the quasifixed inputs, t represents technology, p(p,z,t) represents variable profit that allows for Hicks nonneutral technological change and is defined as:
where x is the vector of variable netput quantities, and Tt is the production possibilities set at time t. The variable profit function is a natural dual description of the technology if one views fixed input endowments and output and variable input prices as given, which is often assumed in international trade theory (Kohli 1993a). Under such conditions, p(·) is linearly homogeneous and convex in variable netput prices, nondecreasing in output prices, and nonincreasing in variable input prices. If the production function exhibits constant returns-to-scale, it is also linearly homogeneous and concave in fixed input quantities (Diewert 1974). From Hotelling's lemma, differentiating P(·) with respect to variable netput prices, when quasifixed input quantities are constant, results in conditional netput supply equations: ![]() where w = w(p,z,t) = where The short-run price and quantity elasticities, E= [emn], associated with the variable profit function can be computed as follows:
where pp = diag[ In the variable profit function, quasifixed input quantities and output and variable input prices are treated as exogenous, while quasifixed input prices and output and variable input quantities are endogenous. Hence, exp = [eih] are the elasticities of output supply and variable input demand with respect to changes in exogenous prices, exz = [eij] are the elasticities of output supply and variable input demand with respect to changes in factor endowments, ewp = [eji] are the elasticities of the inverse quasifixed input demands with respect to changes in exogenous prices, and ewz = [ ejk] are the elasticities of the inverse quasifixed input demands with respect to changes in factor endowments. The submatrices, exz and ewp, are also known as the Rybczynski and Stolper-Samuelson elasticities, respectively (Kohli 1991). All short-run elasticities are functions of (p,z,t). Through the homogeneity properties of the output supply and the variable input demand functions and the maintained hypothesis of constant returns to scale, the price and quantity elasticities are subject to the following restrictions:
In our empirical application, the national sectoral endowment of capital and labor will be treated as being quasifixed in the short run (J=2). If a longer-run perspective is taken in which the supply of either capital or labor is perfectly elastic while the supply of the other factor remains quasifixed, intermediate-run elasticities, (EM), can be calculated from the short-run elasticities, (E). Let the quantity and price of the input that was previously quasifixed but is now variable be q and r, respectively, and the quantity and price of the input which remains quasifixed be y and v, respectively. Then the intermediate-run elasticities are:
where i,h = 1,2,...,I. References |
|
|
|