November 1998 SCSB# 390

TRADE, POLICY AND COMPETITION:
FORCES SHAPING AMERICAN AGRICULTURE PROCEEDINGS


Chapter 9
Measuring the Effectiveness of Nonprice Promotion of U.S. Agricultural Exports
Using a Supply-side Approach


Estimation

Share equations (9.8) and (9.9) are estimated as a separate system for each sector using an iterative version of Hansen's generalized method of moments procedure (GMM) available in TSP 4.3. The estimated error structure accounts for both contemporaneous correlation among equations and second-order serial correlation. The energy and capital equations are omitted from the estimation system in both sectors. Because of singularity of the covariance matrix of complete systems of share equations, iterative three-stage least squares (I3SLS) estimates are invariant to the equations deleted from each system. Initial values for GMM estimation are obtained by first estimating the system using I3SLS.

All parameters for the omitted equations are derivable from the estimated equations through the homogeneity and symmetry conditions. There are 144 system observations (six equations times 24 annual observations) to estimate 33 parameters for the farm sector and 456 system observations (six equations times 76 quarterly observations) to estimate 33 parameters for the food processing sector. Since output prices are simultaneously determined, Canada's GDP, Japan's GDP, the European Community's GDP, the U.S.'s GDP, a multilateral trade weighted value of the U.S. dollar, Moody's Aaa bond rating interest rate, import price, energy price, hired labor or agricultural inputs price, materials or marketing inputs price, self-employed labor or labor quantity, capital quantity, time trend, and a constant are used as instrumental variables in estimation.

Results

The GMM parameter estimates for both sectors are reported in Table 9.2. Nineteen of 33 farm production sector and 21 of 33 food processing sector parameters are significant at the 5 percent significance level. Convexity in variable input and output prices requires that the eigenvalues associated with rows and columns of the Hessian matrix corresponding to outputs and variable inputs be positive. These are computed at the data means and reported in Table 9.3. All are positive, so convexity is satisfied for both models. The quasifixed input eigenvalues are also reported in Table 9.3. Their negative signs satisfy concavity in quasifixed input quantities at the data means for both sectors. Monotonicity requires that predicted output and quasifixed input shares are positive and predicted variable input shares are negative. The predicted shares have the correct signs for all observations in both sectors.

Satisfaction of curvature and monotonicity conditions insures that the estimated models fully conform with the underlying profit-maximization assumption. By also testing for homothetic separability, we determine whether either sector's output for domestic consumption and for export can be aggregated into a single output category as is assumed in other trade models. When data are homothetically separable in a partition, the subset of quantities can be aggregated into a single index and their corresponding prices into another index. It permits consistent two-stage choice modeling. Homothetic separability is tested with each translog variable profit function using the following three-part hypothesis test:

Part I: Ho: biI=0, biF=0, biM=0, YiL=0, Yit=0,biC+ biX=0, i=C,X.

Part II: Ho: biI=0, biF=0, biM=0, YiL=0, Yit=0, bC/bX=biC/ biX, i=C,X.

Part III: Ho: bC/ bX= biC/biX, bC/bX= YCj/ YXj, i = X, I, H or A, M, or R, and j = L, t.

To consistently aggregate domestic bound production and exports, we must fail to reject at least one of the three parts. The calculated likelihood ratio test statistics for the three parts of the test for farm production are 50.92, 64.36, and 21.58, respectively. They are 267.32, 220.26, and 149.62, respectively, for food processing. These results indicate that consistent aggregation of domestic bound production and exports is rejected at the 1 percent significance level (critical values of c2.01,12=26.22 and c2.01,7=18.48) for both sectors. Thus, they should be considered as distinguishable outputs in both sectors, as allowed in the GNP function approach. It should be noted that the GNP function approach is the only one of the popular trade-oriented models that keeps domestic bound production and exports in differentiated categories, as required for consistency with these specification test results. Hence, the suitability of the GNP function approach for modeling U.S. agricultural trade for both the farm and food processing sectors is supported by statistical performance and hypotheses tests. In addition, about two-thirds of the estimated parameters of each model are statistically significant.

The full matrix of the farm sector's short-run elasticities (flexibilities) are reported in Table 9.4. They include the output supply and variable input demand price elasticities, their cross-price elasticities with respect to the quasifixed factor endowments (similar to the Rybczynski elasticities from the Heckscher-Ohlin model [Kohli 1990]), and the price and quantity flexibilities for quasifixed input prices (the former are similar to the Stolper-Samuelson elasticities from the Heckscher-Ohlin model). They are computed at the data means from the estimated parameters using equation (9.4). Approximate standard errors are computed for the elasticities using the delta method. Nearly half of the elasticities are statistically significant at the 5 percent level.

Consistent with the expectation of a convex profit function, all own-price elasticities (flexibilities) have the expected sign. In addition, all for which a standard error is computed are significant. Export supply is barely elastic while the supply elasticity of domestic bound production is inelastic at .48. Except for materials, all variable input demands are inelastic. All cross-price effects with respect to both output prices are positive. Hired labor and energy are significant economic complements. Self-employed labor is a significant economic complement to imports and is an economic substitute for both hired labor and capital. However, although a change in self-employed labor quantity has a large relative effect on the quantity of imports, a change in import price has a trivial effect on self-employed labor price. Capital is a significant economic complement to hired labor and materials and an economic substitute for self-employed labor. Due to the maintained hypothesis of constant returns-to-scale, the own-quantity flexibility of each quasifixed input is of equal magnitude and opposite sign to its cross effect with respect to the other quasifixed input's quantity.

The processing sector's short-run elasticities (flexibilities) are reported along with their approximate standard errors in Table 9.5. Most of the elasticities are statistically significant at the 5 percent level. Again consistent with the expectation of a convex profit function, all own-price elasticities (flexibilities) have the expected sign. All for which a standard error is computed are significant. Opposite to the farm sector, the supply of domestic bound production in the food processing sector is highly elastic (3.64) and export supply is inelastic (.45). Half of the variable input demands are elastic. Except for energy's response to export price, all significant cross-price effects with respect to both output prices are positive. And, the response of both outputs and all inputs to a change in the price of domestic bound production is significant. The variable inputs are consistently economic complements to all other inputs, both variable and quasifixed, and most relationships are significant. The quasifixed inputs are significant substitutes to each other. While a change in the price of domestic bound production, agricultural inputs, or marketing inputs generally has a significant and highly elastic impact on all variable netput quantities and quasifixed input prices, a change in energy price has a trivial impact on the quantities demanded of other variable inputs and on the prices of quasifixed inputs.

Intermediate-run own-price elasticities computed from equation (5) are reported in Table 9.6 for both sectors.1 Capital is kept quasifixed in the first column for each sector, and labor or self-employed labor is quasifixed in the second column. All input demand and output supply elasticities have the expected signs. Allowing capital to vary has a much greater impact on the intermediate-run elasticities than allowing self-employed labor to vary for the farm sector. Results are mixed for the processing sector. Consistent with Le Chatelier's principle, each of the intermediate-run variable input demand elasticities is more elastic than in the short run.

Model Simulations

Once estimated, equations (9.8) and (9.9) can be transformed from shares to levels by multiplying each share equation by variable profit and dividing by the respective price. The transformed models can then be simultaneously solved to determine welfare effects of alternative policies on farm producers and food manufacturers. The farm sector's nontraded output (C) and the food processing sector's agricultural food input demand (A) explicitly link the two U.S. sectors through supply and demand, endogenizing the price of agricultural inputs to the processing sector and agricultural outputs from the production sector. The model is then augmented with additional equations representing export demand for processed food and a market clearing identity for the world market to endogenize export quantity and price in the food processing industry. Export demand for processed food is specified in Cobb-Douglas form so that the parameters are interpreted as elasticities. Export demand for processed agricultural products is given by:

xx =  
 apxc pab,  (9.10)

where px is export price, pa is promotional expenditures, b is the advertising export elasticity, and c is the price elasticity of export demand. The intercept a is calibrated so that model solutions are near the observed mean export value for the food processing sector when export demand and export advertising elasticities are equal. Simulation results indicate that changes in producer welfare resulting from a change in Market Promotion Program (MPP) expenditures are not overly sensitive to the point chosen for calibrating the export demand function. Advertising expenditures are taken as the mean MPP expenditures for the 1989-1992 period. During that period, $200 million was appropriated for MPP activities each year (Ackerman, Smith, and Suarez 1995). The MPP requires producer groups and food manufacturers to pay approximately 50 percent of the total promotional cost. To assess the welfare effects of the MPP, we compare model simulations using alternative own-price and advertising elasticities of demand with and without the $200 million MPP subsidy. All other exogenous variables are set at their respective mean values. Changes in each sector's variable profit (i.e., returns to the quasifixed inputs) associated with alternative advertising and own-price export demand elasticities are reported in Table 9.7.

Assuming (a) promotional activities affect demand for only one period, (b) administrative costs for the MPP are zero, (c) there is no free riding by competitors, and (d) tax revenue sufficient to cover the MPP costs can be collected with no deadweight loss, a profitable return for the program is anything above a $200 million rise in the sum of both sectors' variable profits. This occurs in the upper right portion of Table 9.7 where the ratio of the advertising elasticity to the absolute value of the own-price elasticity of export demand is equal to or greater than unity. This result coincides with the observation by Kinnucan et al. (1995) that nonprice promotion is most effective when the advertising elasticity is high and the export demand elasticity is low. As the price elasticity of export demand rises, the break-even point for MPP expenditure drops below the diagonal where the ratio of the advertising elasticity to the absolute value of the own-price elasticity of export demand is one. For example, when the own-price elasticity of export demand is -0.3, an advertising elasticity of 0.2 results in a positive return for MPP expenditures. Except at high export demand elasticities and very low advertising elasticities, the farm sector benefits more from the MPP than does the processing sector. This suggests that, under certain conditions, the MPP may provide a reasonably efficient scheme to enhance farm profitability.

Including MPP administrative costs and the deadweight loss associated with collecting taxes to cover program costs would shift the breakeven point in Table 9.7 further to the northeast. Assuming that it costs $0.20 to $0.50 in deadweight loss to collect $1.00 in tax revenues (Alston and Hurd 1990), the breakeven point for the MPP would shift to between $240 and $300 million. Alternatively, including long-run benefits from promotional activities would move the breakeven point more toward the southwest part of Table 9.7. However, most evidence suggests that the benefits of advertising are short lived (Fuller et al. 1992; Duffy 1983).

Several studies estimate advertising elasticities for specific commodities but none for the food aggregate. Dewbre et al. (1987) report an advertising elasticity of 0.086 for Australian wool imported to the United States Williams (1985) reports short- and long-run advertising elasticities for exports of soybeans as 0.02 and 0.08, respectively. Kinnucan and Forker (1986) report a domestic advertising elasticity of 0.056 for milk in New York City. Solomon and Kinnucan (1993) report advertising elasticities for U.S. exports of cotton to be 0.25 for Japan, 0.19 for Hong Kong, and 0.12 for the Pacific Rim. Duffy (1983) reports domestic own-price demand and advertising elasticities of -0.36 and 0.05 for beer, -0.85 and 0.11 for spirits, and -1.13 and 0.15 for wine, respectively, in the U.K. Chang and Green (1989) report domestic own-price demand and advertising elasticities of -0.50 and 0.103 for meats, -0.027 and 0.123 for dairy products, -0.044 and 0.035 for cereal products, -0.072 and 0.031 for fruits and vegetables, and -0.037 and 0.240 for other foods at home for the United States

In nearly all cases, the own-price elasticity estimate is greater in absolute value than the associated advertising elasticity. Duffy (1987) also concludes that advertising campaigns exert weak effects relative to the influence of price changes. In addition, the elasticities for aggregate food are expected to be smaller in absolute value than for individual commodities. These estimates suggest that the most likely combination of own-price and export demand elasticities are in the lower left of Table 9.7, probably below the breakeven ratio of advertising to own-price elasticity. Interestingly, advertising and own-price elasticities in relevant portions of this range indicate farmers receive almost no benefit from public MPP expenditures. For example, using Chang and Green's estimated elasticities for meat suggests agricultural producers would receive only $2 million in benefits from a $200 million subsidy.

Notes

1Intermediate-run elasticities with respect to the remaining quasifixed input are all 1.0 because of the assumption of constant returns-to-scale. Long-run elasticities are undefined by the same assumption.

References


 return to top of page

  return to Chapter 9

return to contents